menu

Aerial Predators?

Are major airlines that temporarily lower their fares to squeeze out their low-fare niche-market startup competitors guilty of predatory pricing?

In early 1995 American Airlines (AA)'s regular fare between Dallas and Kansas City was $108 before low-cost start-up Vanguard Airlines Inc. entered the market. AA, by far the largest airline serving the Dallas/Fort Worth hub, responded by matching Vanguard's fares at $80 and almost doubled the number of daily flights to 14. When Vanguard finally gave up in December 1995, American restored its old fare and scaled back the number of flights. Similar fate met two other start-up carriers that offered low-fare service from Dallas to various mid-western cities.

In May 1999, the government filed an anti-trust lawsuit against AA alleging "predatory pricing" But the U.S. District Judge ruled against the Justice Department and in favor of AA.

According to the US law, a firm is guilty of predatory pricing if it sells products or services for less than its average variable cost (AVC) and makes up for the resulting losses by raising prices above competitive levels once its rivals are forced out of the market. AA, currently the largest airline in the world after its recent acquisition of Trans World Airlines, says that it had every right to match the fares offered by its contender. And with fares lower, it was justified in adding more planes to meet increased demand. It also says that it only raised fares to the previous level when the rivals left, not to a higher level to recoup losses.

But if at lower fares AA was able to carry more passengers without incurring a loss under competition, it must be making a handsome profit when it can restore the old fares by reducing flights under monopoly?

The reason why AA could out-compete its start-up rivals is because it could successfully defend its market share. Given the same low fares between AA and its rivals, passengers understandably stayed with AA because its large network of connecting flights between hundreds of cities offered convenience that start-ups serving only a niche market could not match. But the substantial costs of creating and operating this network can be covered only by ensuring a sufficient volume of passengers and by dividing these costs across the carrier's many routes. Lowering fares permanently may not generate enough revenues to cover these high network fixed costs.

If the niche markets were big enough to allow the start-ups to gain a large enough market share to be viable, AA might have been forced to permanently lower its fares just to be competitive.

References:

  • Carney, Dan. "Predatory Pricing: Clearing for takeoff." Business Week,5/14/2001.
  • George, L. "A Ruling for 'Predators' and Consumers." The Wall Street Journal, 5/3/2001.
  • Heaster, Randolph. "Fight or flight." The Kansas City Star, 5/1/2001.
  • Wilke, John and McCartney, Scott. "American Airlines Wins a Victory." The Wall Street Journal, 4/30/2001.

Glossary:

  • variable cost
    Cost that varies with the level of output or action taken. Under short-run diminishing returns, variable cost will eventually increase at an increasing rate even though fixed cost stays the same.
    diagram
  • fixed cost
    Cost that stays the same in the short run regardless of the level of output or action taken. Graphically, fixed cost is represented by a horizontal line from the cost axis in the cost-output space.
    diagram
  • monopoly
    An industry with a single seller selling a unique (or patented) product and has enough market power to practice effective price discrimination.
    diagram

Topics:

Costs and opportunities, Regulation

Keywords

aerial predators, American Airlines, antitrust, antitrust law, average variable cost, entrants, entry, fixed costs, leader, marginal cost, monopoly, network, predatory pricing, rivals