Liquidity Trap
Even with short-term interest rates close to zero, the US economy has failed to respond to cheap money because of anemic bank lending.
In a succession of cuts, the Fed reduced the short-term interest rates to near zero in late 2008 (WSJ 12/17/2008). If the Fed’s intention was to revive the economy from the housing bust, it has not succeeded. Bank lending to small businesses remained anemic. Consumer credit has been tightened. And unemployment rates have remained high at about 10%.
The Fed is powerless to lower the interest rates further unless it is willing to drive interest rates to below zero. Negative interest rates mean that a given amount of bank deposits will shrink absolutely over time. So it pays bank depositors to spend their money sooner than later. But savers could always keep their money under their mattress and “earn” zero nominal interest instead of negative nominal interest. In other words, the US economy is in the vice of a classic liquidity trap.
Banks are reluctant to lend because they need to conserve cash to back up bad loans made earlier. In other words, they are mired in a debt trap. And they are afraid new loans may turn bad in the uncertain economic environment. If the yield curve is very flat (see The Yield Curve), the longer-term interest rates may not be high enough to justify the risk of making longer-term new loans. But if the yield curve is steep, then it is safer simply to borrow short from the central bank to buy safe government bonds (WSJ 12/17/2009). In Japan, the flat yield curve has discouraged lending. In the US, the steep yield curve has encouraged the purchase of government bonds rather than lending. For example, the yield spread between a 10-year Treasury bond and a 1-year Treasury bill was more than 3 percentage points (NY Times 4/15/2010). So the low short-term interest rates pursued by the Fed ended up fattening the bottom line of the shaky banks rather than stimulating lending.
If cheap money ends up lowering the cost of government deficit financing, monetary policy has in effect become a back-door fiscal policy. And if budget deficit financing leads to higher inflation rates than the interest rates, real interest rates could be driven down to negative territories. Indeed, the $787 billion stimulus package may not be big enough to significantly contribute to economic growth, but the positive inflation rates in 2010 are enough to drive the real short-term interest rates to below zero (usinflationcalculator.com). Some economists are seriously suggesting the Fed’s targeting a higher inflation rate to jump start the economy. That will surely drive the real short- term interest rates deeper into the negative territories.
But with the US public debt/GDP ratio projected to be over 100% in the next few years, any aggressive economic stimulus may threaten the credit rating of Treasury bonds and increase their yield costs.
Notes:
- Update: 3//27/2015. The US unemployment rate has declined to 5.5% around February 2015. But the employment to working-age population ratio of 77% is still way below the above 80% high in the late 90's. The Fed policy of easy money is still in a state of flux. (qz.com. 11/4/2014. "<a href="http://qz.com/286213/the-chart-obama-haters-love-most-and-the-truth-behind-it/">Labor-force Participation.</a>")
References:
- NY Times. "How much of the world is in a liquidity trap?" 3/17/2010.
- NY Times. "Low rates good for banks, but pity the saver."
- WSJ. "Fed cut rates near zero to battle slump." 12/17/2008./
- WSJ. “Obama vs the banks.” 12/17/2008.
- useconomy.about.com. "Economic stimulus package." 6/3/2010.
- usinflationcalculator.com. "Current inflation rates: 2000 – 2010."
Glossary:
- bondA fixed-income (coupon) debt security issued by corporate or government borrowers. At issue, the coupon interest rate varies directly with the duration (maturity) of the bond and inversely with credit-worthiness of the issuers and is tied to the face value of the bond. The market price of the bond after initial issue may change depending on supply and demand while the coupon stays the same. So the yield (coupon/market price) varies in opposite direction with the market price.
- nominal interest rateIt is the face-value interest rate before discounting for price inflation.
- nominal vs realA nominal value is expressed in historical money terms. By contrast, a real value has been adjusted from a nominal value to remove the effects of general price level changes from the base reference year.
- real interest rateIt is the difference between the nominal interest rate and the inflation rate. The real interest rate could be negative if the inflation rate is higher than the nominal interest rate.
- Gross domestic product (GDP)Gross domestic product (GDP) measures the total market value of all final goods and services produced in a country in a given year, plus exports, minus imports. "Gross" means that capital depreciation allowances have not been netted out from the total.
- real vs nominalA nominal value is expressed in historical money terms. By contrast, a real value has been adjusted from a nominal value to remove the effects of general price level changes from the base reference year.
- budget deficitAn excess of expenditures over revenues.
- liquidity trapA situation whereby the interest rates could not go any lower no matter how much the central bank tries to increase money supply and that even the very low interest rates could not stimulate any more economic activities.
- yieldThe return on an investment. In the case of bonds, the yield that is of interest is the current yield, which measures the fixed coupon payment as a percentage of the current market price of the bond. The current yield varies inversely with the current market price of the bond. The current yield can be contrasted with the coupon rate, which measures the fixed coupon payment as a percentage of the face value of the bond at issue date.
Topics:
Keywords
inflation rate, interest rate spread, interest rates, lending, Liquidity trap, loans, negative interest rates, nominal interest rates, real interest rates, yield curve