Bond Free?
Treasury bonds are important instruments in regulating the money supply.
The US federal deficit is estimated to be $1.6 trillion in 2010, $1.3 trillion next year, and $8.5 trillion for the next 10 years.
Commentators are deeply worried that such huge debt burdens might erode America’s global economic, political and military power since a large part of the debt must be funded by foreign countries.
This concern looks ironic from barely 10 years ago when the US Treasury and the Federal Reserve were troubled by ballooning budget surpluses. To stop the cash flood, the Treasury drastically scaled back the volume and frequency of Treasury bond sale. In November 2001, the Treasury finally announced that it will no longer sell 30-year bond, long the benchmark of the US bond market.
These budget surpluses have since been squandered away by the Bush tax cuts, two foreign wars in the Middle East and related national security expenditures. The Great Recession precipitated by the credit binge put a final nail in the surplus coffin.
But the fleeting budget surplus nevertheless opened a rare window into the role Treasury bonds play in the money market.
Treasury bonds play an indispensable role in regulating the supply of money. The Fed increases the supply of money by buying short-term Treasuries from securities dealers. If the cash-flooded Treasury no longer needs to sell bonds to borrow money and is instead retiring existing bonds from the market, the Fed could no longer increase the money supply by buying Treasury bonds.
The Fed could, of course, buy other non-Treasury securities if it is desperate to pump money into the money market. The credit crunch in the Great Recession offers a rare glimpse into what kinds of financial assets the Fed could buy. Specifically, they are longer-term Treasury bonds, government-guaranteed mortgage-backed securities and even private commercial paper from troubled financial institutions under the policy of “quantitative easing.” Quantitative easing is a desperate attempt to flood the market with money when even near zero short term interest rates are still powerless to revive the anemic economy. When longer-term securities are purchased instead of the typically shorter-term bonds, quantitative easing has the additional effect of lowering longer-term interests.
References:
- BW. "For the Fed, the downside of being debt free." 10/9/2000.
- BW. "Bob Rubin’s bond bind." 4/19/1999.
- New York Times. "Fed plans to inject another $1 trillion to aid the economy." 3/18/2009.
- WSJ. "Deficit balloons into national-security threat." 2/2/2010.
- WSJ. "Fed has more ammunition after firing rate-cut bullets." 11/24/2008.
Glossary:
- bondA fixed-income (coupon) debt security issued by corporate or government borrowers. At issue, the coupon interest rate varies directly with the duration (maturity) of the bond and inversely with credit-worthiness of the issuers and is tied to the face value of the bond. The market price of the bond after initial issue may change depending on supply and demand while the coupon stays the same. So the yield (coupon/market price) varies in opposite direction with the market price.
- budget surplusAn excess of revenues over expenditures.
- quantitative easingA way for the central bank to increase the money supply by buying lower-quality securities from the market when very low short-term interest rates are no longer sufficient to revive the weak economy.
- RRReserve ratio. The fraction of money reserve required to back up a bank loan expressed as a percentage.
- budget deficitAn excess of expenditures over revenues.
Topics:
Keywords
budget deficit, budget surplus, debt, interest rate, money supply, quantitative easing, Treasury bonds